A Review of Lawrence Goodwyn's Democratic Promise
@Jargoeauxgne
Democratic Promise: The Populist Moment in America
Democratic Promise: The Populist Moment in America
Lawrence Goodwyn
In the time of American history known as the Gilded Age, when the
economy underwent a transformation of rapid growth and consolidation,
while a remaining class of independent farmers struggled against the
towering new structures of industry and finance, the Populist Movement
emerged in an attempt to secure the policies and reforms necessary for
that independent class to survive. It very nearly survived and succeeded
but ultimately did not, and the story of those failures is both
frustrating and painful. I expected Goodwyn's book to be about the
entire swath of postbellum radical politics but it actually took a
rather narrow scope: the agrarian political movement which arose and
died from the mid-1880's to the mid-1890's, known as the Populists,
which itself originated from the Farmer's Alliance movement which
started in the late 1870's. There were other similar movements such as
the Greenback party, which took place more in Yankee states and pursued
an ethos which might be considered “Cathedral-like”, predictably meshing
economic priorities (currency reform) with social ones (suffrage,
electoral reform). No, Democratic Promise is about the Populist Party,
which, in the beginning, was led and organized with focus, acuity and
total commitment to the principle of economic reform (mainly currency
reform), with the end goal being a class of small-holding farmers
liberated from the liquidating and consolidating pressures of high
finance. This book, is among other things, a glimpse of a uniquely
American future that was forever lost to us. More importantly it was
lost to them, and what's most crushing: it was lost more for reasons of
cowardice, stupidity, ignorance, and betrayal than for the competence of
opposing interests. This review is written in part out of innocent
historical curiosity and interest, but also partly because anyone with
an interest in political organization would benefit from learning the
mistakes of the past.
To give some context for the time: silver was demonetized in 1873,
and the monetary system of the time was molded by the National Bank Act,
in which banking was divided into three tiers, the banks in subsequent
tiers being made to use the notes from preceding tiers as a fraction of
their reserves. In this way, currency could be made uniform across the
country and responsive to changes in demand, smaller banks pyramiding
note-issue off that of larger banks'. It also consolidated the country's
monetary fate in the banks occupying this high tier, which by design
excluded all banks not located in New York City. The normal M.O. for
farmers in this period was to buy all the necessities of the job at the
“furnishing man” and always on credit. In many cases the furnishing man
did not offer the option to farmers to see the difference in ultimate
price between buying in cash and buying on credit, or even the option to
buy in cash at all; furnishing was always on credit. Thus, farmers were
at the mercy of credit conditions at all times; when they restocked at
the furnishing man, when they warehoused their goods come harvest, and
as they paid off their mortgages. Most of the time, farmers would pledge
their crop for credit at the store, and when harvest came and it wasn't
enough to pay off the debts, they would simply sink deeper and deeper
into debt, until “the Man” would come to own their land.
The Populist Moment began as a cooperative movement in Texas, Kansas
and other spots around the South, although the real ideological core of
it all was in Texas and centered around a man named Charles Macune. In
the beginning, they were adamant that the movement, called “The Farmer's
Alliance” was not to be a political one but a purely economic one in
which farmers got together, educated each other, and found ways to get
around the extortionate system of middle-manning and usury. In some ways
they actually succeeded, as when they pooled their resources to buy the
materials and means necessary for jute sacks, which were used to
package their harvests. They bought the raw jute from foreigners and
bought the machinery for making sacks and got around the “Jute Trust” as
they call it, providing a tangible benefit for all the members of the
Farmer's Alliance. But as time went on and as their understanding both
of economic theory and of the emergence of a hierarchical economic
system centered around the big banks of the country, they realized that
there was no way forward other than through political solutions. What
catalyzed this realization was when Charles Macune went around the
country, to different banks in neighboring states, looking for a deal
where the Farmer's Alliance would be floated the credit to warehouse its
members' crops itself, rather than going through the middlemen, who
paid them the one liquidation harvest-time price but sold at the
normalized year-round price and made a killing. Macune's efforts to find
a deal at any bank were thwarted as, apparently, a circular had been
sent through the banking system advising against patronizing any radical
“anarchistic” movements such as the Farmer's Alliance. Evidently they
had kicked up enough of a fuss to warn the commercial interests
surrounding them to prepare themselves and had found out the hard way
that mere collective self-help would be identified by banks and
middlemen as unacceptable; the yeomen class retaining anything more than
the minimum value of their product necessary for reproduction (and
oftentimes less than that) was unacceptable to the commercial and
financial interests latched onto American agriculture. Macune returned
to the Texas Farmer's Alliance organization and spread the word that no
non-political solutions remained for them. He would go to his grave a
firm believer that the Populists should not start a third party but
instead work within the Democratic party to orient it towards currency
reform. He was also the main currency theorist of the movement and
provided its fundamental pillar of economic reform: the Sub-Treasury
Plan.
Many historians of this era quizzically refer to the Sub-Treasury
Plan as a mere means of getting the credit necessary to farmers to
warehouse their goods and thus obviate the aforementioned “Two Price
System” - the warehouser buying all the crops at rock-bottom harvest
prices while selling them off at a normalized year-round price - which
so much robbed them of the fruits of their labor. The Sub-Treasury Plan
was in fact a total reformulation of the country's currency system. As
many banking school advocates put forward, the expedience of the system
of privately created credits is that the money supply expands in
response to changes in growth and population. The result of the
Sub-Treasury Plan would be not only to provide the credit to farmers to
store and sell off their own crops at cooperatively-owned Farmer's
Alliance warehouses, but would also be an injection of currency into the
economy at a low interest rate and at quantities the banks were
unwilling to supply. The policy proposed that enough currency be
provided such that the price level would triple. The Sub-Treasury Plan,
mislabeled by historians not understanding the nature of our currency
system, was not an agricultural reform, it was a reform at the most
fundamental level of economy, meant to obviate the need for private
creditors to supply both credit and money to the economy. We say “both
credit and money” here with the understanding that they were, and are
now, not separate from each other in actuality, but that they are
conceptually distinct and have different economic functions as such. The
Sub-Treasury Plan understood the illegitimacy of the banking system at
root and sought to place it with a rational system of monetary expansion
bypassing the private interests. This plan became the basis for the
Omaha Platform, which became the People's Party official policy platform
in 1892, which called for currency reform, utilities nationalization,
immigration restrictions, labor laws and electoral reform; a
comprehensive program of political economy to excise economic rents and
increase the value of labor.
The Sub-Treasury Plan, as proposed by Texas Allianceman and currency
theorist Harry Tracy, had two planks: the land loan plank and the
warehouse and elevator plank. Both were to be administered through
'sub-treasuries', extensions of the U.S. Treasury operating kind of like
post offices but as banks+warehouses+grain-elevators, in each county of
the country whose average annual production of commodities for the past
two years was at least $500,000 dollars – agricultural hubs,
essentially. Land loans of 80% of the land value, on properties of 200
acres of less would be extended to farmers, up to a maximum of $3000.
The loans would mature after 50 years, be legal tender and carry a
maximum interest rate of 2%. As for the warehousing plank of the plan,
farmers could obtain credit for 80% at 1% interest on the commodities
they brought to market come harvest, which would be stored at
sub-treasury warehouses and grain elevators. These loans would mature
after 12 months and also be legal tender. After a year the loan plus
storage charges, insurance and pro-rated shares of other operating
expenses had to be paid to the sub-treasuries. The purpose of the land
loans was to increase volume of money in circulation to $50 per capita,
while the commodity loans' purpose was to stabilize short-term commodity
prices by allowing farmers to “middleman” their own crop and “prevent
the congestion of money in cities and to make the volume of money adjust
itself to the demands of business at all times and places.” We note
here that agriculture as a share of American employment was by this
point still significant and it is thus not too much of an overstatement
to take agricultural credit demand as a proxy for demand in general.
It's also worth noting that the system of private created credits has
always rested on the defense that it allows the money supply to expand
in response to the increasing needs of commerce, the implication being
that alternative systems whereby the money supply is expanded via public
means would be by fiat and thus cause miscoordinations between demand
and supply of money. We see here that the Sub-Treasury Plan is one
instantiation of the principle of publicly-supplied money that provides
adequate money supply at next-to-no-cost (what most called “at-cost”,
meaning at the cost of administration and accounting, legitimate labor
costs in the business of lending) and in response to shifts in demand.
As a final note, we see that the Sub-Treasury Plan had no provision for
the elimination of privately-created bank-monies and we might speculate
that, at a time when the main concern was inadequate money supply,
eliminating monies from circulation was a lesser priority and not worth
the criticisms of socialism it would invariably draw.
When they set off to become a political party, there was little
agreement internally on what would be done. Party fathers such as Macune
wanted it to stay strictly within the Democratic party, others such as
Jerry Simpson, William Peffer, William Lamb and Alonzo Wardall wanted it
to become its own party. After a string of failures in which populists
pushed Democrats to carry their platform, pushed them into electoral
victory and saw the Democrat candidates turn around and throw away the
platform, they realized that a 3rd party was the only option. Democrats
like James Hogg or Benjamin Tillman gladly accepted the enthusiasm of
agrarian ire but were both ignorant and contemptuous of Populist
enthusiasm. In the case of the former, he railed on about the farmers'
problems but offered no solution, in the case of the latter he actually
endorsed the Sub-Treasury Plan in public speeches and then did nothing
once inaugurated. The Populists came to realize that only people who had
taken the time to understand the monetary system, and who shared in the
misery of the bankrupt farmer, would understand the importance of the
Omaha Platform, and stick to it no matter what. Populism became a 3rd
party movement, once again, out of necessity.
Around this time, the Silver Question started to occupy the
spotlight in American politics. The effects of the Crime of '73
(demonetization of silver) were still sorely felt and many felt that
re-monetization would bring an end to all the ills that had occurred
since then. There was an attractive logic to it all: demonetization
caused a shrink in the money supply, remonetization would bring it back
up to snuff. Powerful political machines in Nevada and California
started to spring up, with bimetallism (AKA the remonetization of
silver) as the fundamental plank of their platforms. The problem here
was that Silver would only address the issue of money supply under
private currency, but it wouldn't address all the other issues. Silver,
with its wealthy mining interest donors, started to suck wind out of the
Populist movements' sails. Hordes of small-brained Americans with no
time to understand the currency system but with plenty of appetite to go
and get silver-rich instantly in the western states swarmed to the
bimetallic political movements. As the populist movement grew as a
political movement, it faced two connected key pressures. One was that
it had grown faster than the cooperative movement, which was the basis
of the community, good-will, mutual aid and education of the movement.
Two was that there were so many newcomers who had little understanding
of the Sub-Treasury Plan and the currency system who were even rising to
power in Populist party positions in states afflicted with
silver-mania, or just states which had a weak cooperative movement and
thus weak lecture circuit. William Allen was one such as these: ignorant
on the currency question, easily swayed by the silver argument, elected
Senator of Nebraska by the Populist Party movement. His ignorance
extended so far that at one party convention he accused the Omaha
Platform people, that is to say the educated and committed segment of
the population at the convention, of being shills for Wall Street. Too
many dimwitted and confused people were allowed into the party and into
the positions of authority, and once they arrived there, they sabotaged
the platform. In 1894, Herman Taubeneck of Illinois, the party's
national chairman, announced that the time had come to ditch the 'isms
and the “wild theories” of the Omaha Platform. Goodwyn refers to figures
such as these as part of a “Shadow Movement” within the party, which is
to say, a movement of people who were never educated, never part of the
cooperatives, and often only seeking their own self-interest or the
interest of the silver magnates in latching on to the party. It was
clear at this point that there was a crisis within the movement.
Populism finally died when it decided to throw its support behind
William Jennings Bryan, who elected for his Vice President a banker from
Maine, instead of the faithful Populist Tom Watson, whom was promised
in exchange for Populist support. Bryan, like many others in the shadow
movement, had no understanding of the currency system, and simply
rallied against Gold because, we might speculate, it played well with
the crowd. Proposals based on economic theory did not play well with
crowds because first they had to be educated, and this was all part of
the painstaking process of the cooperative movement. Once the Populist
Party had gotten big enough to attract people without first putting them
through the process of the cooperative movement, whereby they would be
inculturated and indoctrinated, it stepped too quickly, it accepted the
popularity too willingly, and forgot to safeguard to things that made it
both rational and successful in the first place. Populists put their
support behind Bryan without having any leverage to make any demands of
him after his hypothetical election; they simply trusted that he would
understand the importance of the issue and act on it. Ultimately he
never got the opportunity, but it's safe to say he would have failed in
that commitment. They were eventually able to get Tom Watson of Georgia
onto the Bryan ticket but it was too little too late. The energies of
the party had been expended, sacrificing their base and their principles
to make enough alliances and connections to rally up one climactic
burst of political power for 1896. This can largely be blamed on the
ignorant “Shadow Movement” people like William Allen and Herman
Taubeneck.
It's amazing how in American history grifters and frauds are
omnipresent figures in grassroots politics. I don't suppose it's much
different anywhere else but the parallels in populist history and
contemporary dissident right history were uncanny. I think there are
number of important lessons to be learned from this tale: one is that
the success of the Populist's party was based on the cooperative
movement, something that gave people a life, a source of help, a source
of community and education and belonging. Once Populism became larger
than the cooperative, it lost its integrity and its ability to
ideologically police itself, which is essential. Two, connected with the
former point, is that you cannot allow the wrong people to be in charge
of your organizations. Obvious I know, and yet surprisingly it happens
often enough that it bears repeating. Enough of the electoral successes
of Populism were based on alliances with democrats or republicans such
that the foundational plank of the party started to be called into
question, especially as silver became more viable politically. A
movement must accept a minimum of gifts from outside parties and vet its
members ruthlessly if it is to achieve its original animating goals.
Third is that you cannot make deals with other parties without the
leverage to force them to give what they promised. If the deal is that
you pay up front and get the goods later on, don't take it. This episode
I think is instructive of organizational principles in general but
especially of the principle that size means nothing if the original
ideology is sacrificed. In the era of Trump, many are willing to trade
away the things that matter in return for the sensation that “We are
winning” and these are the people that need to be discarded. Bronze Age
Pervert recently said something to the effect of: “Ignore ideology. We
know who we are and we know who they are; that is all that's important
now, that we fight them.” I would recommend against this.
Fun fact: Tom Watson, who was a lawyer, was approached by the Frank
family of Georgia (yes, that Frank family) to defend their son in the
murder case. He declined.
Comments
Post a Comment